Lecture 29 Cumulative Prospect Theory II
- Non-linear preferences (contd.)
- Principle of diminishing sensitivity: impact of given change in probability diminishes with its distance from the boundary
- Evaluation of outcomes - Boundary to distinguish losses and profits = reference point
- Evaluation of uncertainty - two natural boundaries (corresponding to certainty scale)
- certainty
- impossibility
- E.g. \(0.9 \to 1.0\) or \(0 \to 0.1\) has more impact than \(0.3 \to 0.4\) or \(0.6 \to 0.7\)
- \(\implies\) Diminishing sensitivity, concave near 0 and convex near 1 "\(\sim\) shaped"
- For uncertain prospects:
- subadditivity for very unlikely
- super-additivity for near certainty
- very small probabilities are either greatly overweighted or neglected altogether
-
Scaling
- K&T suggested $$v(x) = \begin{cases} x^\alpha \ & \text{if } x \geq 0 \ -\lambda(-x)^\beta & \text{if } x \lt 0 \end{cases} $$
- \(\alpha:\) coefficient of diminishing marginal sensitivity to gains
- \(\beta:\) coefficient of diminishing marginal sensitivity to losses
- We are referring these two as exponents
- \(\lambda:\) coefficient of loss-aversion
- Functional forms of weighting function
-
\[ w^+(p) = \dfrac{p^\gamma}{(p^\gamma + (1-p)^\gamma)^{1/\gamma}} \]
-
\[ w^-(p) = \dfrac{p^\delta}{(p^\delta + (1-p)^\delta)^{1/\delta}} \]
- \(\gamma\) and \(\delta\) determine the curvature function, different for losses and gains.
- When a non-linear regression procedure was used to estimate parameters:
- The median exponents (\(\alpha = \beta\) ) \(=0.88\)
- The median \(\lambda = 2.25\) indicating loss aversion
- For the weighting function, \(\gamma = 0.61\) and \(\delta = 0.69\)
- concave and steep at low
- overweight for very small probabilities
- convex after: shallow in the middle range steep at high
- underweight moderate and high probabilities
- CE > EV: risk seeking
- CE < EV: risk aversion
- CE = EV: risk neutral
- concave and steep at low
- Empirical evidence
- CE: average amount the subjects were ready to pay (say $78) to obtain an EV of $95 so risk averse.
- Gain, high \(p \to\) Averse
- Loss, high \(p \to\) Seeking
- Gain, medium \(p \to\) Averse
- Loss, medium \(p \to\) Seeking
- Gain, low \(p \to\) Seeking
- Loss, low \(p \to\) Averse
- Improvements offered by CPT
Specification of choice under uncertainty EUT CPT Objects of choice Probability distribution over wealth Prospects framed in terms of gains and losses Valuation rule \(E[U]\) \(V(f) = V(f^+) + V(f^-)\) Characteristic of the map \(: \text{Uncertain Event} \to \text{Subjective}\) \(U \sim\) convex function of wealth Value function: s-shaped
Weighting function: inverse s-shaped- Curvature of weighting function: reflection pattern of attitude to risky prospects
- Overweighting of small probabilities: lottery and insurance
- Underweighting of high probabilities: risk aversion in choice between probable gains vs sure win.
- Curvature of value function: risk-aversion of gains, risk seeking for losses
- Asymmetry of value function: loss aversion, extreme reluctance to accept mixed prospects
- Shape of weighting function: certainty effect
- The Value function
- \(r \neq 0\) (if \(r=0\), its the original K&T value function)
-
\[v(x) = \begin{cases} (x-r)^\alpha & \text{if } x\geq r \\ -\lambda(r-x)^\beta & \text{if } x \lt r \\ \end{cases}\]
-
- Application - Asian Disease Problem 1 ^83c303
- Asian disease expected to kill 600 people
- Two alternative programs to combat the disease
- \(A:\) (200) people will be saved (for sure)
- \(B:\) \((600, \dfrac{1}{3})\) else no one
- Choices: \(A \to 72\%\) and \(B \to 28\%\)
- \(A\) can be written as \((200,1;400,0)\)
- \(B\) can be written as \((600, \dfrac{1}{3}; 0 \dfrac{2}{3})\)
- Application - Asian Disease Problem 2 ^6cbd95
- Same context
- Two alternatives
- \(C:\) (400) people will die (for sure)
- \(D:\) \((0, \dfrac{1}{3})\) else 600 die.
- Choices: \(C \to 22\%\) and \(D \to 78\%\)
- \(C: (400)\) and \(D: (600, \dfrac{2}{3})\)
- Application Questions
- Few effects
- Framing (reference point changed)
- Certainty
- Reflection (gains and losses are reflections)
- loss aversions
- preference reversal
- Calculate the value functions using functional forms and estimated parameters and check its efficacy
- Problem 1 states "how many lives saved"? \(r=0\)
- Problem 2 states "how many die"? \(r = 600\)
- Value Functions - Problem 1
- \(V(A) = v(200) = 200^{0.88} \cong 105.90\) for \(w^+(1)= 1\)
- \(V(B) = w^+\left( \frac{2}{3} \right)v(0) + w^+(\frac{1}{3})v(600) \cong 67.24\)
- \(V(A) = 105.90 \gt V(B) = 67.24\) and so \(A \succ B\)
- Value Functions - Problem 2
- We see that
- \(V(D) = -165.43 \gt V(C) = -238.28\) and so \(D \succ C\)